(Published in the South China Morning Post on 19 November 2006)
Risk. It's a word thrown around so frequently
in the investment world there's risk-adjusted, systematic risk, specific risk,
and we all know that beta, alpha, cost of equity and the Sharpe Ratio have
something to do with it. But what is it actually?
In the 1950s, the early pioneers of
modern portfolio theory (MPT), such as Harry Markowitz, Merton Miller and
William Sharpe, asked themselves this question when they came up with the
simple hypothesis that investors get rewarded (with higher returns) for taking
on greater risk. For this idea to go any further, though, they had to have a
way of quantifiably measuring risk.
They came up with a simple, if controversial,
solution: risk (of any asset) can be measured by the standard deviation of
historic returns (of that asset). In other words, the more volatile the returns
from a given asset the more risky it is.
From this simple assumption - and
several others, such as markets being efficient, that one measure of risk
applies to all investors, that there are no transaction costs - grew MPT and
its flagship, the risk-gauging capital asset pricing model, to this day the
cornerstones of the financial economics curriculum in schools, investment
associations and financial institutions.
For their work in the field of understanding
how asset prices behave, Dr Markowitz, Dr Miller and Dr Sharpe shared the 1990
Nobel Prize in economics. Building upon MPT and work by Robert C. Merton and
others, Fisher Black and Myron Scholes published a paper in 1973 introducing
the options pricing model that bears their name. Its basic assumption is
equities move randomly; that is, their returns are distributed according to the
normal bell curve, which charts the frequency of random walk outcomes.
The model assumes that volatility
does not change much, and prices options as a function of the historic
volatility of the underlying asset.
This worked well in normal market
conditions, where changes in volatility were gradual, but if volatility
abruptly increased it would break down. Dr Merton and Dr Scholes - members of
the team that in 1994 established the ill-fated Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM)
hedge fund received the Nobel Prize in 1997 for this and other work.
Best-selling financial author Roger
Lowenstein, in When Genius Failed, his excellent book on the US$4 billion
collapse of LTCM, said: "Every investment bank, every trading floor on
Wall Street, was staffed by young, intelligent PhDs, who had studied under Dr
Merton, Dr Scholes or their disciples. The same firms that spent tens of millions
of dollars per year on expensive research analysts - i.e. stock pickers -
staffed their trading desks with finance majors who put capital at risk on the
assumption the market was efficient, meaning that stock prices were ever
correct and therefore that stock picking was a fraud."
It is now known that a significant
portion of the instructions on Black Monday, October 19, 1987, to sell large
blocks of shares came from black box, or automated, trading programs into which
the Black-Scholes model had been built. The initial fall in markets caused by
Germany's unexpected interest rate increase - and the associated rise in volatility
- triggered a self-fulfilling wave of computer-driven panic. The programs were
spitting out sell instructions assuming the increased volatility was highly
unusual - which in the real world it was not - further increasing volatility and
causing more sell instructions.
In the aftermath of the 1987 crash,
Harvard economics professor Lawrence Summers, later a United States treasury
secretary, remarked to The Wall Street Journal: "The efficient market
hypothesis is the most remarkable error in the history of economic
theory."
And all of this from the simple assumption
that volatility equaled risk. What went wrong?
The dictionary definition of risk is
the possibility of loss.
Applied to financial markets, risk
should mean the probability that an investment - whether a portfolio or an
individual asset - will perform worse than expected.
But whose expectation? After all,
expectation is a subjective quantity. In investing, expectation belongs to the
investor. Everyone is entitled to have a different expectation for their
investments. It is ludicrous to suggest that Warren Buffett and a day trader
would see eye to eye on a particular stock, especially if they were both
holding it at the same time. One would want the stock to grow at a steady pace
over many years, while the other would be happy with a half-point bump before
lunch. Yet MPT posits they should see eye to eye, defining risk as the
objective historic volatility of a given stock. Furthermore, asset price
returns are not normally distributed. In the real world, the supposedly
well-distributed curve has a lump at each end, known as the fat tail (see
chart). The tails describe extreme events - such as Russia's 1998 debt default
that brutally exposed LTCM's weakness – which are not as rare as the theory says
they should be.
The ultimate irony about short-lived
LTCM - the penultimate one being its name - is that two of its partners, Dr
Merton and Dr Scholes, proponents of the Efficient Market Theory, built a model
to take advantage of arbitrage opportunities created by market inefficiencies.
These are not new observations, but
the speed at which old-established theories are debunked is agonisingly slow.
The likes of Mr Buffett who I suspect does not calculate his risks by looking
at historic stock price movements - must hope the pace of change remains slow
and that the Nobel committee continues to bestow its awards on academics
sitting in their ivory towers, far removed from the messy world of nuts, bolts
and corporate profits.
So what is the point of all this? My
advice is to throw away the textbooks and accept that, at least for most
investors, there is no point in worrying about volatility. On the contrary, you
should learn to welcome it, as your shares can't go up without it. The only
sure fact is that over periods of 10 years or more, markets tend to go up, and
that most of this appreciation will be due to rising corporate profits.
Ultimately, the only reliable model
of the real world is the world itself. As University of Chicago economist
Eugene Fama – often thought of as the father of Efficient Market Theory -
famously remarked, life always has a fat tail.
No comments:
Post a Comment